3. Labour Demand

KAT.TAL.322 Advanced Course in Labour Economics

Nurfatima Jandarova

March 13, 2024

Labour demand

Firm decisions about how much labour to hire.

Static model

Static model

Single factor input

Production function \(Y = F(L)\) where \(F^\prime > 0\) and \(F^{\prime\prime} < 0\)

\[ \max_{L} PF(L) - WL \]

FOC: \(F^\prime(L) = \frac{W}{P}\)

Downward-sloping labour demand \(\frac{\partial L}{\partial W} = \frac{1}{PF^{\prime\prime}(L)} < 0\)

Static model

Two factor inputs: conditional factor demand

Cost minimization problem

\(\min_{L, K} C(L, K) = WL + RK\) s.t. \(F(L, K) = \bar{Y}\)

Conditional demand functions \(\bar{K}(W, R, Y)\) and \(\bar{L}(W, R, Y)\)

\[ \frac{F_L(\bar{L}, \bar{K})}{F_K(\bar{L}, \bar{K})} = \frac{W}{R} \quad\text{and}\quad F(\bar{L}, \bar{K}) = \bar{Y} \]

Static model

Two factor inputs: conditional demand elasticities

  • Own-price elasticities: \(\eta_W^L = \frac{\partial \ln \bar{L}}{\partial \ln W} < 0\), \(\eta_R^K = \frac{\partial \ln \bar{K}}{\partial \ln R} < 0\)

  • Cross-price elasticities: \(\eta_R^L = \frac{\partial \ln \bar{L}}{\partial \ln R} > 0\) and \(\eta_W^K = \frac{\partial \ln \bar{K}}{\partial \ln W} > 0\)

  • Elasticity of substitution \(\sigma = \frac{\partial \ln\left(\frac{K}{L}\right)}{\partial \ln \left(\frac{W}{R}\right)} > 0\)

It is also possible to show that

\[ \eta_R^L = \sigma (1 - s) \quad \text{and} \quad \eta_W^L = -\sigma(1 - s) \]

where \(s = \frac{WL}{C}\) is labour share in total cost

Static model

Two factor inputs: unconditional factor demand

\(\max_{Y} PY - C(W, R, Y)\)

Solution: \(P = C_Y(W, R, Y^*), L^* = \bar{L}(W, R, Y^*), K^* = \bar{K}(W, R, Y^*)\)

Total elasticities decomposed into substitution and scale effects:

\[ \varepsilon_W^L = \color{#8e2f1f}{\eta_W^L} + \color{#288393}{\eta_Y^L \varepsilon_W^Y} < 0 \]

\[ \varepsilon_R^L = \color{#8e2f1f}{\eta_R^L} + \color{#288393}{\eta_Y^L\varepsilon_R^Y} \lessgtr 0 \]

Estimations of static model

Empirical strategy

Shephard’s lemma: specify cost function and back out labour demand

Example: translog cost function with \(n\) inputs

\[ \ln C = a_0 + \sum_{i = 1}^n a_i \ln W^i + \frac{1}{2} \sum_{i = 1}^n \sum_{j = 1}^n a_{ij} \ln W^i \ln W^j + \frac{1}{\theta} \ln Y \]

\[ \Rightarrow s^i = a_i + \sum_{j = 1}^n a_{ij} \ln W^j \]

Estimate parameters \(a_{i}, a_{ij}\) and calculate implied elasticities.

Estimations of static model

Main issues

  • Endogeneity

  • General equilibrium

  • Definitions of variables

Estimations of static model

Review by Hamermesh (1996) concludes that \(-\eta_W^L \in [0.15, 0.75]\).

If \(\eta_W^L = -0.30\) and given that \(s \approx 0.7\),

\[ \sigma = \frac{-\eta_W^L}{1 - s} \approx 1 \]

consistent with the Cobb-Douglas production function.

The review also suggests \(-\varepsilon_W^L \approx 1 \Rightarrow\) large scale effect.

Dynamic model

Dynamic model

Adjustment costs

Share of non-wage labour costs
  • Quadratic cost: \(C\left(\Delta L_t\right) = b\left(\Delta L_t - a\right)^2\)

  • Assymmetric convex costs: \(C\left(\Delta L_t\right) = -1 + e^{a\Delta L_t} - a\Delta L_t + \frac{b}{2}\left(\Delta L_t\right)^2\)

  • Linear cost: \(C\left(\Delta L_t\right) = \begin{cases}c_h \Delta L_t & \text{if }\Delta L_t \geq 0\\-c_f \Delta L_t & \text{if }\Delta L_t \leq 0\end{cases}\)

  • Fixed cost

Dynamic model

Quadratic adjustment cost

Continuous time \(\Rightarrow \Delta L_t = \dot{L}_t = \frac{\text{d} L_t}{\text{d}t}\)

\[ \Pi_0 = \int_0^\infty \Pi_t dt = \int_0^\infty \left[F(L_t) - W_tL_t - \frac{b}{2}\dot{L}_t^2\right]e^{-rt}dt \]

Euler equation: \(\frac{\partial \Pi_t}{\partial L} = \frac{\text{d}}{\text{d}t}\left(\frac{\partial \Pi_t}{\partial \dot{L}_t}\right) \Rightarrow b\ddot{L}_t - rb\dot{L}_t + F'(L_t) - W_t = 0\)

Dynamic model

Quadratic adjustment cost

Optimal path: \(\dot{L}_t = \gamma \left[L^* - L_t\right]\) where \(\gamma\) is decreasing in \(b\).

Figure 9.6 Optimal employment over a cycle (Nickell 1986)

Dynamic model

Linear adjustment cost

\[ \Pi_0 = \int_0^\infty \left[F(L_t) - W_tL_t - C(\dot{L}_t)\right]e^{-rt}dt \]

where \(C\left(\dot{L}_t\right) = \begin{cases}c_h \dot{L}_t & \text{if }\dot{L}_t \geq 0\\-c_f \dot{L}_t & \text{if }\dot{L}_t \leq 0\end{cases}\)

Optimal labour demand path is derived from

\[ \begin{cases}F'(L_t) = W_t + r c_h & \text{if }\dot{L}_t \geq 0 \\ F'(L_t) = W_t - r c_f & \text{if }\dot{L}_t < 0\end{cases} \]

Dynamic model

Linear adjustment cost

Figure 9.10 Optimal employment over the cycle (Nickell 1986)

Estimations of dynamic model

Empirical strategy for adjustment cost specification

Quadratic adjustment cost

  • Assume linear quadratic production function

  • Estimate \(L_{it} = \lambda L_{i, t - 1} + X_{it} \beta + \mu_i + \varepsilon_{it}\)

    • accounting for correlation between \(L_{i, t - 1}\) and \(\mu_i + \varepsilon_{it}\)

Other adjustment costs and production functions

  • Estimate Euler equation directly

  • Current employment \(L_t\) depends on past and future variables

  • Appropriate econometric methods (Hamilton 1994 book)

Estimations of dynamic model

Some key results

  • Adjustments happen fast (1-2 quarters) (Hamermesh 1996, chap. 7)

  • Dynamic substitutes: utilization of capital increases with \(L_t - L^*\)

  • Hours of work are adjusted faster than number of workers

    Figure 1 from Houseman and Abraham (1993) (adjustment to demand shocks)

Minimum wages and employment

Minimum wage and employment

What do the models we have considered so far predict?

  • lower labour demand (both compensated and uncompensated)

  • (maybe) higher labour supply

Any “problems” with these conclusions?

Typically not supported by empirical evidence!

Minimum wage and employment

Card and Krueger (1994)

On April 1, 1992 minimum wage in New Jersey \(\uparrow\) from $4.25 to $5.05.
It stayed at $4.25 in Pennsylvania.

Minimum wage and employment

Card and Krueger (1994): Difference-in-differences

  1. Compare before and after:
    \(E_{t1}^{NJ} - E_{t0}^{NJ}\) = 0.59 (se = 0.54)

Minimum wage and employment

Card and Krueger (1994): Difference-in-differences

  1. Compare before and after:
    \(E_{t1}^{NJ} - E_{t0}^{NJ}\) = 0.59 (se = 0.54)
  2. Compare NJ and PA:
    \(E_{t}^{NJ} - E_{t}^{PA}\) = -2.89 (se = 1.44)

Minimum wage and employment

Card and Krueger (1994): Difference-in-differences

  1. Compare before and after:
    \(E_{t1}^{NJ} - E_{t0}^{NJ}\) = 0.59 (se = 0.54)
  2. Compare NJ and PA:
    \(E_{t}^{NJ} - E_{t}^{PA}\) = -2.89 (se = 1.44)
  3. Diff-in-diff:
    \(\left(E_{t1}^{NJ} - E_{t0}^{NJ}\right) - \left(E_{t1}^{PA} - E_{t0}^{PA}\right)\) = 2.75 (se = 1.34)

Minimum wage and employment

Jardim et al. (2022)

Seattle \(\uparrow\) min wage from $9.47 up to

  • $11 in April 2015
  • $13 in January 2016

Causal design:

  • synthetic control: weighted average of other counties that match pre-Seattle
  • nearest neighbour matching: find “closest” worker outside of Seattle matching treated worker in Seattle

Minimum wage and employment

Jardim et al. (2022): synthetic control

Minimum wage and employment

Jardim et al. (2022): synthetic control

Minimum wage and employment

Jardim et al. (2022)

  • Negative effect on hours worked stronger than on employment
  • Experienced workers are better off

However,

  • Potentially cascading effect
  • Excluded large low-wage employers (like McDonald’s) (monopsony)

Reich, Allegretto, and Goddy (2017)

same policy + synthetic control = no change in employment

Minimum wage and employment

Monopsony

Source: Figure 3 from Brown (1999)

Minimum wage and other margins

Review in Clemens (2021)

Summary

  • Basic static and dynamic models of labour demand

  • Application to minimum wage policy

    • Ongoing research (little consensus)
    • Clear that basic models are insufficient
    • Typical frameworks: heterogeneous labour, monopsony
    • Non-wage margins important and can interact with labour supply

Next: Human Capital

References

Bell, Brian, and Stephen Machin. 2018. “Minimum Wages and Firm Value.” Journal of Labor Economics 36 (1): 159–95. https://doi.org/10.1086/693870.
Brown, Charles. 1999. “Chapter 32 Minimum Wages, Employment, and the Distribution of Income.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, 3:2101–63. Elsevier. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)30018-3.
Cahuc, Pierre. 2004. Labor Economics. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press.
Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. 1994. “Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania.” The American Economic Review 84 (4): 772–93. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2118030.
Clemens, Jeffrey. 2021. “How Do Firms Respond to Minimum Wage Increases? Understanding the Relevance of Non-Employment Margins.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 35 (1): 51–72. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.35.1.51.
Clemens, Jeffrey, Lisa B. Kahn, and Jonathan Meer. 2018. “The Minimum Wage, Fringe Benefits, and Worker Welfare.” NBER Working Paper. Working Paper Series. May 2018. https://doi.org/10.3386/w24635.
Clemens, Jeffrey, and Michael R. Strain. 2020. “Implications of Schedule Irregularity as a Minimum Wage Response Margin.” Applied Economics Letters 27 (20): 1691–94. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2020.1713978.
Coviello, Decio, Erika Deserranno, and Nicola Persico. 2022. “Minimum Wage and Individual Worker Productivity: Evidence from a Large US Retailer.” Journal of Political Economy 130 (9): 2315–60. https://doi.org/10.1086/720397.
Draca, Mirko, Stephen Machin, and John Van Reenen. 2011. “Minimum Wages and Firm Profitability.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 3 (1): 129–51. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.3.1.129.
Dustmann, Christian, Attila Lindner, Uta Schönberg, Matthias Umkehrer, and Philipp vom Berge. 2022. “Reallocation Effects of the Minimum Wage*.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 137 (1): 267–328. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjab028.
Hamermesh, Daniel S. 1996. Labor Demand. Princeton University Press.
Houseman, Susan N, and Katharine G Abraham. 1993. “Labor Adjustment Under Different Institutional Structures: A Case Study of Germany and the United States.” NBER Working Paper 4548. Cambridge, MA. October 1993. https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w4548/w4548.pdf.
Jardim, Ekaterina, Mark C. Long, Robert Plotnick, Emma van Inwegen, Jacob Vigdor, and Hilary Wething. 2022. “Minimum-Wage Increases and Low-Wage Employment: Evidence from Seattle.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 14 (2): 263–314. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20180578.
Ku, Hyejin. 2022. “Does Minimum Wage Increase Labor Productivity? Evidence from Piece Rate Workers.” Journal of Labor Economics 40 (2): 325–59. https://doi.org/10.1086/716347.
Leung, Justin H. 2021. “Minimum Wage and Real Wage Inequality: Evidence from Pass-Through to Retail Prices.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 103 (4): 754–69. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00915.
Luca, Dara Lee, and Michael Luca. 2019. “Survival of the Fittest: The Impact of the Minimum Wage on Firm Exit.” NBER Working Paper. Working Paper Series. May 2019. https://doi.org/10.3386/w25806.
Nickell, S. J. 1986. “Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Labour Demand.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, 1:473–522. Elsevier. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(86)01012-X.
Reich, Michael, Sylvia Allegretto, and Anna Goddy. 2017. “Seattle’s Minimum Wage Experience 2015-16.” SSRN Electronic Journal. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3043388.
Renkin, Tobias, Claire Montialoux, and Michael Siegenthaler. 2022. “The Pass-Through of Minimum Wages into U.S. Retail Prices: Evidence from Supermarket Scanner Data.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 104 (5): 890–908. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00981.